Question:
TQ 4.1: If a buyer breaches a sales contract and the price goes down, what are the seller’s options? If the seller breaches and the price goes up, what are the buyer’s options?
TQ 4.2: In State v. Ernst & Young, why did the court find that the state had not met its duty to mitigate damages?
TQ 4.3: Why didn’t the duty to mitigate damages apply in Gianetti v. Norwalk Hospital?
TQ 4.4: You agree to sell your used car to a neighbor for a price of $2,000, but then you have a change of heart. How likely is it that a court would force you to go through with the transaction, as opposed to simply paying your neighbor the difference between the contract price and the price of a comparable used car? Would your answer be different if the car was a vintage used car worth $50,000?
DQ 4.1: Article 39 of the Restatement (Third) of Restitution reads as follows:
If a breach of contract is both material and opportunistic, the injured promisee has a claim in restitution to the profit realized by the defaulting promisor as a result of the breach. Liability in restitution with disgorgement of profit is an alternative to liability for contract damages measured by injury to the promisee.
Commentators have described section 39’s adoption as the equivalent of a “quiet revolution” that “is breathtaking in its potential transformation of the traditional contractual landscape.” Caprice L. Roberts, Restitutionary Disgorgement as a Moral Compass for Breach of Contract, 77 U. Cin. L. Rev 991, 993 (2009). What is so revolutionary about this provision? How does it differ from the traditional approach to contract damages described in your textbook?
Provisions in the Restatement are not legally binding unless and until they are adopted in a particular jurisdiction. Would you encourage your jurisdiction to adopt section 39? Why or why not?
DQ 4.2: Do you think the result in Gianetti v. Norwalk Hospital was fair to the hospital? Why or why not?